Characterizing political participation
Democracy is government by the people. Ideally, people choose their representatives based on evaluating the candidates’ agenda and determining which candidate is the best for them. However, choosing the best candidate based on individual efforts is tiresome. In practice, people gather in friends and family meetings and share their political thoughts stemming from individual thinking, people’s social network and media. Consequently influencing and getting influenced by the network of political information.
As people get influenced by the network, tailored propaganda can skew political thought. If, say, the media publish easily shareable, emotionally arousing content, this skewing action might evolve into a political epidemic, and in return skew public thought drastically towards the desired political direction. This process may lead to a party gaining vast majority of votes in a region, thereby having the same echoing thoughts getting reinforced (echo chambers) and consequently having extremist polarization. Although measuring how media influences voters is a cumbersome task, we can measure the vote-wise polarization (or dominance) of a party at a region with a simple metric.
In this blog post, we present two metrics to measure a region’s polarization in political thought and divergence of one region’s political behavior from the average – based on election results. Polarization is measured by the normalized entropy and divergence is measured by the Kullback-Leibler divergence (metrics widely used in communications and computing). Let’s start with the normalized entropy.
KL divergence measures how far a distribution (P) is from the reference distribution (Q). We will use this metric to measure how different a province’s political thought from the country-wide political thought. If KL divergence is low, then province’s thoughts are not much different from the country-wide thought. If high, then country-wide thought is insufficient in explaining the province’s thought.
Use Case: Turkey
Let’s try our metrics on Turkish Parliamentary Elections. Turkey is a country which hosts multiple debates that effectively polarize the country. Each debate has one or more parties associated with it. We will not describe which party is associated with which debate in order not to skew the analysis. Yet it is important to note that one particular division lies on the Secular/Conservative axis.
We observe that Turkish variety in political thought declined until 2018 elections where October 2015 election has the lowest average variety. In 2018, average variety increased for the first time since 2002. But average variety is not the whole story. 2018’s variety distribution is bimodal. That is, some of the cities, has average variety around 0.5 whereas some has around 0.65. We will talk about the bimodality in the next section. Let’s focus on the divergence now.
Each divergence histogram is concentrated close to zero. It is okay. We expect most of the cities to have political thought distribution close to the country-wide thought. In the end, cities’ collective decision forms the country votes. Importance is in the tail of these distributions, magnified in little rectangles. Tail distributions indicate the amount of marginal thoughts. We can see that between 2007 and 2015, there were greatly marginal cities. In 2018, this marginality reduced in magnitude but the amount of marginal cities remained to be substantial. This is also associated with the bimodality. Let’s investigate it.
Bimodality in 2018 Elections
We can see that either AKP (ruling party) or CHP (main opposition party) has the majority of the votes in most of the mainstream cities. Whereas, HDP has most of the marginal cities. Cities with larger voting population have greater variety compared to smaller ones. We see lower variety thoughts are concentrated on cities with AKP or HDP majority. Suggesting, these parties have strong vote basis in their respective cities. By investigating the scatter plot, we can see, mainly, HDP majority cities create the bimodality in 2018 elections. Choropleth maps can help us identify the spatial patterns of the bimodality.
Let’s Put It On The Map
Map illustrates that the western Turkey is richer in political variety compared to the rest of the cities in the country. On the other hand, the southeastern part of Turkey advocates for fewer types of political thought.
Figure 3 and 4 show that both the high and low variety cities cluster spatially. Also, southeastern region has a different political character that cannot be explained by the average political variety in Turkey and the region advocates for this strongly. Let’s try to identify why.
Factors Influencing the Entropy and Divergence
According to the first column (horizontal axis is log scale), as voter population increases, political variety increases for AKP and CHP majority cities. On the other hand, political variety decreases with increasing voter population in HDP majority cities. Divergence of AKP and CHP majority cities decrease as voter population increases and vice-versa for the HDP majority cities.
MADI is the amount of personal income after tax deduction. For AKP and HDP majority cities, political variety increases as MADI increases and vice-versa for CHP. That is, AKP and HDP has stronger vote basis in cities with lower MADI, and CHP holds a stronger vote basis in cities with high MADI. As MADI increases, divergence of HDP majority cities reduce greatly. This trend is also followed by AKP majority cities but with less slope. Finally, CHP majority cities’ divergence increases with increasing MADI.
Gini Index is used to measure the income inequality. Lower values indicate better income equality. Variety of AKP majority cities increases with higher Gini Index and vice-versa for CHP and HDP. Suggesting AKP voting basis is concentrated on cities with better income equality. HDP majority cities’ divergence increases drastically with lower income equality. This trend is also followed by CHP but with less slope, vice-versa for the AKP.
Conclusions
Entropy and KL divergence are two metrics that can explain voter variety of countries, irrespective of the parties and spatial scale.
Analysis on the Turkey shows western coastal regions of Turkey has high political variety. Central Anatolian regions have medium variety and southeastern regions have low variety, compared within Turkey. Moreover, southeastern region has drastically different voter profile compared to the country-wide votes.
When variety of AKP majority voters is compared to Voter Population, MADI and Gini Index, we see that AKP’s variety increases with larger voter population, greater MADI and worse income equality. CHP’s variety increases with larger voter population, lower MADI and with better income equality. HDP’s variety increases with smaller voter population, greater MADI and better income equality.
Since AKP is the ruling party and CHP is the main opposition party, AKP and CHP majority cities have low divergences. On the other hand, HDP majority cities’ divergences are substantial. What can minimize the divergence of HDP are having a smaller voting population, greater MADI or better income equality.
Caveats
This study is a reductionist one. Politics of Turkey is a complex system where individuals vote based on intricate social decision making. These results are found by analyzing three decision variables. The reality is associated with much more and there is no guarantee on these three variables being the ones that explain much of the variance.
Even assuming these three variables are the ones that perfectly explain city wide voting variety and divergence for 2018 elections, there is time and scale associated with this system. How variety in a district or neighborhood is affected is still unknown and how the found relationships change over time (dynamics) is still a mystery. Therefore, since this post is about a social system, please remember that this post does not show how the system works, but is a mere proxy for it.
Thank you for your time.